3.2 PROBLEMS OF THE INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES - AN OUTLOOK
There is a need, especially in a number of the developing
countries, for extensive agrarian reforms because there are
such great discrepancies between the existing agrarian structures
and what is required for socioeconomic development to take
place that comprehensive and radical measures would be necessary
in order to bridge the gap. This is why the subject "agrarian
reforms" is usually discussed in connection with developing
countries.
This, however, should not lead to the belief that the industrial
countries have no agrarian problems. If despite this fact
agrarian reforms are hardly ever mentioned in the context
of industrial countries, it is mainly due to two factors.
Firstly, the problems are not primarily such as would demand
a change in land ownership and thus call for an agrarian reform
in its narrow sense. Moreover, the instruments and institutions
that are available in the industrial countries often make
it possible to take the necessary measures step by step without
necessitating sweeping reforms. It is true that such adaptions
are in some cases either undertaken only hesitatingly, or
not at all; However, the fact that the agrarian sectors are
generally quite small makes it possible for the industrial
countries to neglect undertaking the necessary measures on
the basis of political or other grounds because the overall
economy is in a position to pay the cost of this, sometimes,
irrational behaviour.
This cannot cover up the fact that the agrarian question
has led, in some cases, to considerable and constantly growing
problems in the industrial countries and that the measures
undertaken to solve them have an influence on the conditions
in the developing countries. For these reasons, an outlook
will be drawn up here without any claim to being complete
and comprehensive in order to show a few essential problems
in the relationship between man and land in the industrial
countries.
One very important difference in comparison to the developing
countries is the fact that, most cases, the agricultural sector
in the present industrial countries developed after industrialization
had taken place. This was possible because at the beginning
of industrialization the population density was comparatively
low, food imports were available to meet any deficiencies,
and, finally, emigration overseas functioned as a blowoff
valve when the pressure became too strong. At the beginning
of industrialization, economic and psychological factors led
to an exodus of labour from agriculture that in Germany, for
example has continued until today. Agriculture tried to compensate
for the shortage of manpower, whichhbad always existed in
a few overseas countries, with migrant workers and, soon thereafter,
mechanization. This process which had already taken place
in other countries and on the large farms before the Second
Warld War also spread to the small farms after the war. Thus
agriculture was faced with a new obligation; it had to pay
the cost of mechanization. Furthermore, the exodus from agriculture
could only be stopped by satisfying not only the income expectations
of the agricultural labourers (which were based on industrial
wages), but of the farmers' sons as well.
The way to do this was to increase production and productivity
in the process of commercializing agriculture. To be a farmer
was no longer a way of life, but an occupation. Rational considerations
determined the management of the farm and resulted in a division
of labour, specialization, and cooperation among the farms,
or even in the decision to give up agriculture if the farm
area was too small. In addition to mechanization, intensifying
agriculture brought about increased utilization of new, technologies,
especially fertilizers, pesticides, and high quality seeds,
etc. These farm inputs are of industrial origin and must,
therefore, be purchased. This results in an increases interlacing
of agriculture and the non agricultural sectors and, thus,
increased dependence. Those farms,in particular, with highly
qualified managers, good soil conditions, and a favourable
market position achieved astounishing increases in productivity
and income in this process.
The process, however, did not take place without having side
effects that caused problems, or at least raised some questions.
In the course of this process of adaption, quite a few farms
were ruined. A lack of land, unfavourable natural conditions,
disadvantageous market positions, and inadequate managing
abilities forced some farm managers to give up, or impelled
the successors to turn to another occupation. Thus, between
1950 and 1980 the number of farms in the Federal Republic
of Germany decreased by 50%. Other industrial countries went
through a similar development In particular, a large number
of farms with less than 20 hectares of land at their disposal
stopped operations and, thus, made it possible for other farms
to increase the size of their cultivable area. All in all,
this process was taken in step fairly well as it took place
at a time when industry was booming. Still, this should not
hide the fact that the process caused a great deal of suffering
and misery in concrete, individual cases.
The increases in farm size made it possible, on the average,
to meet the growing income expectations. Considerable differences,
however, developed within agriculture itself. In some regions-particularly
mountainous regions-the unfavourable natural conditions set
narrow limits to efforts to increase productivity and incomes.
Since there are only few non- agricultural job opportunities
in some of these regions, large sections of the population
migrated to urban centres, which resulted in entire regions
becoming depleted. As it was usually the young, active sections
of the population that migrated, whereas the old people remained,
this also led to further deterioration of the economic and
social structures.
Likewise, the price-cost ratio made it possible for some
types of farms to earn astoundingly high incomes, wheras others
conversely earned only way below average incomes. Individual
performance, market position, and varying effects of government
price and subsidizing policies have led to considerable disparities
with agriculture in other words, to large differences in income
among the farms.
Finally, among the forms of unsuitable agrarian structures
that should also be mentioned are, in particular, the widespread
types of tenancy found in the countries of Southern Europe
as well as the employment of inexpensive alien employees and
migrant workers in agriculture in Europe and the USA.
Despite all of the structural changes and intensification
of agriculture, the income earned in large sections of agriculture
was unsatisfactory and was raised by state subsidies to promote
income. These measures, which can be found in one form or
another in nearly all industrial countries (in Germany, agriculturists
had at one time a legal right to compensation that raised
their income to the level of comparative non-agricultural
wages) improved the incomes of many farmers, it is true; however,
at the same time they created new problems. Agriculture has
became a dependent section of the overall economy which regards
demands for price increases as a nuisance. Many of the subsidies
have furthermore led to unintended sideeffects. The most important
in this context is overproduction. The subsidized prices were
so attractive to many producers that they resulted in production
increases that surpassed the demand. The outcome was additional
expenses for storing these products and, in some cases, further
subsidies in order to promote marketing outside the country.
Larger surpluses, especially in cereals, led to the development
of a systematic policy of cereal exports and food aid to the
countries of the Third World. This is, in some cases, often
a blessing and prevents hunger in countries that do not produce
an adequate supply of food. Too often, though, the food deliveries
cause a decline in the recipient countries' efforts to raise
their own production. Certainly, this would mean a long, costly
process in concrete cases. But wouldn't the production in
some of the developing countries also be higher if they were
granted the same arount of aid to use to increase their production
that is otherwise given in the industrial countries? At least
there is the danger that price subsidies granted for the purpose
of raising agricultural income in the industrial countries
might in the end prevent the desired domestic production in
the developing countries from taking place.
On the other hand, pressure to continue high production policies
in the industrial countries also comes from another side.
To an increasing extent, maximum yields are not only the product
of efforts made in agriculture itself, but also the result
of prior and subsequent services performed by industry and
the service sector. These sectors apply pressure to increase
the employment of inputs and services in order to enhance
their own econanic success. This can easily be too much. Exaggerated
usage of pesticides and weed killers has detrimental effects
an the environment and health. Additives in feed may have
negative effects on quality or even endanger health. Breeding
cannot only increase susceptibility and, thus, risk, but also
reduces the variety of types. Peasant agriculture has indeed
proved its sense of responsibility, but regarded globally
and particularly in the case of commercial forms of agriculture,
the dangers cannot be denied.
The increased interdependence between the sectors not only
makes agriculture dependent, but it also reduces the amount
of land available to agriculture. The necessary transport
network and industrial sites, dwelling places and recreational
areas for the non-agricultural population reduce agricultural
land to a considerable extent In the Federal Republic of Germany,
the area of land under cultivation shrank between 1949 and
1976 by 900,000 hectares. It should be mentioned, however,
that this includes substandard land first cultivated during
the war.
The new functions the rural areas fulfil in an industrial
society also create new tasks. More and more townspeople prefer
a home in the country and commute to their place of work.
Furthermore, the rural areas are becoming recreation areas
for the urban population, a role that can only be fulfilled
as long as the countryside is protected and preserved. These
tasks also have consequences for the agrarian structure and
farming.
Recently, an additional question has arisen. To a considerable
extent, the great increases in production are dependent upon
the utilization of fossil fuels. Tractors, fuel, fertilizer,
and pesticides would not be available without oil. Even if
there is enough oil in the future, the prices will increase
drastically. This will lead, without fail, to considerable
increases in the price of agricultural products. It will be
possible in the industrial countries to burden the consumer
with these price increases. Is this also true of the surplus
production that is marketed commercially in, subsidized,or
granted as aid to the developing countries? From what point
on is it sensible and desirable to invest the same means in
the developing countries?
Under the right conditions, the same amount of capital could
lead to a greater increase in production, while at the sane
time being produced where it will be consumed. What consequences
would this have for the domestic food supply in times of crisis?
The goal of this short outlook is not to say that all of
the circumstances described above must, can, or should be
changed. The aim is just to raise questions and, thus, indicate
that in the industrial countries as well, the constant changes
in the economic, social and political conditions necessitate
continual reconsideration of the relationships between man,
land, capital and technology.
|