2.2.1.1 Abolition of the 'Intermediaries'
In 1951, as the first agrarian reform measure, the intermediaries,
the numerous revenue collectors who often did not have a definite
function, lost their rights. Considerable problems cropped
up because of the large number of very different cases. This
measure did not aim at abolishing the ownership of large amounts
of land, but only of specific rights. Among those who were
affected were numerous small zamindars who earned low incomes
from a few acres of land. Often, this was their only source
of income, and they had come legally into possession of it,
either through purchase or inheritance. Illegal methods my
also have played a role when the titles were acquired, but
some jagirs were conferred in return for important services.
For all the above as well as constitutional reasons, the government
took over these rights in return for quite high compensations
whose rates increased inversely to the amount of income earned
from the land. The compensation was paid in installments without
binding conditions for its use and burdened the government
in India with Rs. 6.3 billion and in Pakistan with Rs. 360
million.
An exceptional situation arose in the former jagirs which
had often been very badly administered. Not only was the government
forced to make considerable investments in health services,
schools, etc.to bring these regions ro the same level as the
rest of the country, but ithbad to take over the jagirdars'
staff as well as pay their pensions. An additional burden
resulted from the fact that many jagirdar families were not
in a position to make a new start in life. After having spent
the sum they had received as compensation, they became destitute,
and it became necessary to draw up special rehabilitation
programmes.
Since the measures aimed at abolishing specific legal conditions,
land which belonged to the same people under other legal conditions
was not affected by this measure. Nor was land expropriated
that was self-cultivated. To provide them with a basis for
existence, those who until then had not cultivated any land
themselves, were granted the right to dismiss tenants of land
up to three times the size of an average family farm before
expropriation was enforced. The term "self cultivation"
was not clearly defined and gave rise to many manipulations.
The zamindars began to let hired labourers cultivate land
they tad leased to tenants until then and even persuaded illiterate
tenants to give up their rights. This abuse took on such proportions
that special laws had to be passed to cancel the voluntary
waives made during the last years. In spite of this, the number
of protected tenants decreased considerably.
Despite all these problems, by the mid fifties, the intermediaries
had been abolished in the two countries. The farmers in these
regions more than 20 million in India alone had come into
direct contact with the government whose tax revenues increased
considerably. However, the above described higher burdens
largely counterbalanced this increase. For the farmers, this
meant freedom from the arbitrariness of the zamindars and
of the numerous "abwabs," but the tax burden remained
the same with the only difference being that the government
was now the recipient. At any rate, the legal status of the
"occupancy tenants" was now clearer. However, only
those who were well off could avail themselves of the possibility
of purchasing land rights since most of the actual tenants
lacked the necessary funds to that end. The larger cultivators
could thus enlarge their farms and became the new lessors
in the village. These measures did not affect in any way the
large number of subtenants who had leased land from occupancy
tenants.
|